欢迎来到课桌文档! | 帮助中心 课桌文档-建筑工程资料库
课桌文档
全部分类
  • 党建之窗>
  • 感悟体会>
  • 百家争鸣>
  • 教育整顿>
  • 文笔提升>
  • 热门分类>
  • 计划总结>
  • 致辞演讲>
  • 在线阅读>
  • ImageVerifierCode 换一换
    首页 课桌文档 > 资源分类 > DOC文档下载  

    经济金融企业管理外文翻译外文文献英文文献.doc

    • 资源ID:8179       资源大小:153.50KB        全文页数:36页
    • 资源格式: DOC        下载积分:10金币
    快捷下载 游客一键下载
    会员登录下载
    三方登录下载: 微信开放平台登录 QQ登录  
    下载资源需要10金币
    邮箱/手机:
    温馨提示:
    用户名和密码都是您填写的邮箱或者手机号,方便查询和重复下载(系统自动生成)
    支付方式: 支付宝    微信支付   
    验证码:   换一换

    加入VIP免费专享
     
    账号:
    密码:
    验证码:   换一换
      忘记密码?
        
    友情提示
    2、PDF文件下载后,可能会被浏览器默认打开,此种情况可以点击浏览器菜单,保存网页到桌面,就可以正常下载了。
    3、本站不支持迅雷下载,请使用电脑自带的IE浏览器,或者360浏览器、谷歌浏览器下载即可。
    4、本站资源下载后的文档和图纸-无水印,预览文档经过压缩,下载后原文更清晰。
    5、试题试卷类文档,如果标题没有明确说明有答案则都视为没有答案,请知晓。

    经济金融企业管理外文翻译外文文献英文文献.doc

    -附录 【原文】 Upgrading in Global Value Chains The aim of this paper is to e*plore how small- and medium-sized Latin American enterprises ( SMEs) may participate in global markets in a way that provides for sustainable growth. This may be defined as the highroad to petitiveness, contrasting with the low road, typical of firms from developing countries, which often pete by squeezing wages and profit margins rather than by improving productivity, wages, and profits. The key difference between the high and the low road to petitiveness is often e*plained by the different capabilities of firms to upgrade. In this paper, upgrading refers to the capacity of a firm to innovate to increase the value added of its products and processes (Humphrey & Schmitz, 2002a; Kaplinsky&Readman, 2001; Porter, 1990). Capitalizing on one of the most productive areas of the recent literature on SMEs, we restrict our field of research to small enterprises located in clusters. There is now a wealth ofempirical evidence (Humphrey, 1995; Nadvi &Schmitz, 1999; Rabellotti, 1997) showing that small firms in clusters, both in developed and developing countries, are able to over e some of the major constraints they usually face: lack of specialized skills, difficult access to technology, inputs, market, information, credit, and e*ternal services. Nevertheless, the literature on clusters, mainly focused on the local sources of petitiveness ing from intracluster vertical and horizontal relationships generating collective efficiency (Schmitz, 1995), has often neglected the increasing importance of e*ternal link ages. Due to recent changes in production systems, distribution channels, and financial markets, and to the spread of information technologies, enterprises and clusters are increasingly integrated in value chains that often operate across many different countries. The literature on global value chains (GVCs) (Gereffi, 1999; Gereffi& Kaplinsky, 2001) calls attention to the opportunities for local producers to learn from the global leaders of the chains that may be buyers or 1 . z.-producers. The internal governance of the value chain has an important effect on the scope of local firms upgrading (Humphrey& Schmitz, 2000). Indeed, e*tensive evidence on Latin America reveals that both the local and the global dimensions matter, and firms often participate in clusters as well as in value chains (Pietrobelli& Rabellotti, 2004). Both forms of organization offer opportunities to foster petitiveness via learning and upgrading. However, they also have remarkable drawbacks, as, for instance, upgrading may be limited in some forms of value chains, and clusters with little developed e*ternal economies and joint actions may have no influence on petitiveness. Moreover, both strands of literature were conceived and developed to overe the sectoral dimension in the analysis of industrial organization and dynamism. On the one hand, studies on clusters, focusing on agglomerations of firms specializing in different stages of the filiere, moved beyond the traditional units of analysis of industrial economics: the firm and the sector. On the other hand, according to the value chain literature, firms from different sectors may all participate in the same value chain (Gereffi, 1994). Nevertheless, SMEs located in clusters and involved in value chains, may undertake a process of upgrading in order to increase and improve their participation in the global economy, especially as the industrial sector plays a role and affects the upgrading prospects of SMEs. The contribution this paper makes is by taking into account all of these dimensions together. Thus, within this general theoretical background, this study aims to investigate the hypothesis that enterprise upgrading is simultaneously affected by firm-specific efforts and actions, and by the environment in which firms operate. The latter is crucially shaped by three characteristics: (i) the collective efficiency of the cluster in which SMEs operate, (ii) the pattern of governance of the value chain in which SMEs participate, and (iii) the peculiar features that characterize learning and innovation patterns in specific sectors. The structure of the paper is the following: in Section 2, we briefly review the concepts of clustering and value chains, and focus on their overlaps and plementarities. Section 3 first discusses the notion of SMEs upgrading and then 2 . z.-introduces a categorization of groups of sectors, based on the notions underlying the Pavitt ta*onomy, and applied to the present economic reality of Latin America. Section 4reports the original empirical evidence on a large sample of Latin American clusters, and shows that the sectoral dimension matters to e*plain why clustering and participating in global value chains offer different opportunities for upgrading in different groups of sectors. Section5 summarizes and concludes. 2. CLUSTERS AND VALUE CHAINS During the last two decades, the successful performance of industrial districts in the developed world, particularly in Italy, has stimulated new attention to the potential offered by this form of industrial organization for firms of developing countries. The capability of clustered firms to be economically viable and grow has attracted a great deal of interest in development studies. 1 In developing countries, the sectoral and geographical concentration of SMEs is rather mon, and a wide range of cases has since been reported. 2 Obviously, the e*istence of acritical mass of specialized and agglomerated activities, in a number of cases with historically strong roots, does not necessarily imply that these clusters share all the stylized facts which identify the Marshall type of district, as firstly defined by Becattini (1987). 3 Nonetheless, clustering may be considered as a major facilitating factor for a number of subsequent developments (which may or may not occur): division and specialization of labor, the emergence of a wide network of suppliers, the appearance of agents who sell to distant national and international markets, the emergence of specialized producer services, the materialization of a pool of specialized and skilled workers, and the formation of business associations. To capture the positive impacts of these factors on the petitiveness of firms located in clusters, Schmitz (1995) introduced the concept of collective efficiency (CE) defined as the petitive advantage derived from local e*ternal economies and joint action. The concept of e*ternal economies 4 was first introduced by Marshall in his Principles of Economics(1920). According to Schmitz (1999a), incidental e*ternal economies (EE) are of importance in e*plaining the petitiveness of industrial clusters, but there is also a deliberate force at work: consciously pursued joint action 3 . z.-(JA).Such joint action can be within vertical or horizontal linkages. 5 The bination of both incidental e*ternal economies and the effects of active cooperation defines the degree of collective efficiency of a cluster and, dynamically, its potential for fostering SMEs upgrading. Both dimensions are crucial: Only incidental, passive e*ternal economies may not suffice without joint actions, and the latter hardly develop in the absence of e*ternal economies. Thus, our focus is on the role of intracluster vertical and horizontal relationships generating collective efficiency. However, recent changes in production systems, distribution channels and financial markets, accelerated by the globalization of product markets and the spread of information technologies, suggest that more attention needs to be paid to e*ternal linkages. 6 Gereffis global value chain approach (Gereffi, 1999) helps us to take into account activities taking place outside the cluster and, in particular, to understand the strategic role of the relationships with key e*ternal actors. From an analytical point of view, the value chain perspective is useful because (Kaplinsky,2001; Wood, 2001) the focus moves from manufacturing only to the other activities involved in the supply of goods and services, including distribution and marketing. All these activities contribute to add value. Moreover, the ability to identify the activities providing higher returns along the value chain is key to understanding the global appropriation of the returns to production. Value chain research focuses on the nature of the relationships among the various actors involved in the chain, and on their implications for development (Humphrey & Schmitz, 2002b). To study these relationships, the concept of governance is central to the analysis. At any point in the chain, some degree of governance or coordination is required in order to take decisions not only on what should be, or how something should be, produced but sometimes also when, how much, and even at what price. Coordination may occur through arms-length market relations or non market relationships. In the latter case, following Humphrey and Schmitz (2000), we distinguish three possible types of governance:(a) network implying cooperation 4 . z.-between firms of more or less equal power which share their petencies within the chain; (b) quasi-hierarchy involving relationships between legally independent firms in which one is subordinated to the other, with a leader in the chain defining the rules to which the rest of the actors have to ply; and (c) hierarchy when a firm is owned by an e*ternal firm. Also stressed is the role played by GVC leaders, particularly by the buyers, in transferring knowledge along the chains. For small firms in less developed countries (LDCs), participation in value chains is a way to obtain information on the need and mode to gain access to global markets. Yet, although this information has high value for local SMEs, the role played by the leaders of GVCs in fostering and supporting the SMEs upgrading process is less clear. Gereffi (1999), mainly focusing on East Asia, assumes a rather optimistic view, emphasizing the role of the leaders that almost automatically promote process, product, and functional upgrading among small local producers. Pietrobelli and Rabellotti (2004) present a more differentiated picture for Latin America. In line with the present approach, Humphrey and Schmitz (2000) discuss the prospects of upgrading with respect to the pattern of value chain governance. They conclude that insertion in a quasi-hierarchical chain offers very favorable conditions for process and product upgrading, but hinders functional upgrading. Networks offer ideal upgrading conditions, but they are the least likely to occur for developing country producers. In addition, a more dynamic approach suggests that chain governance is not given forever and may change because(Humphrey & Schmitz, 2002b): (a) power relationships may evolve when e*isting producers, or their spin offs, acquire new capabilities;(b) establishing and maintaining quasi-hierarchical governance is costly for the lead firm and leads to infle*ibility because of transaction specific investments; and (c) firms and cluster soften do not operate only in one chain but simultaneously in several types of chains, and they may apply petencies learned in one chain to supply other chains. In sum, both modes of organizing production, that is, the cluster and the value chain, offer interesting opportunities for the upgrading and modernization of local 5 . z.-firms, and are not mutually e*clusive alternatives. However, in order to assess their potential contribution to local SMEs innovation and upgrading, we need to understand their organization of inter firm linkages and their internal governance. Furthermore, as we e*plain in the following section, the nature of their dominant specialization also plays a role and affects SMEs upgrading prospects. 3. THE SECTORAL DIMENSION OFSMEs UPGRADING (a) The concept of upgrading The concept of upgradingmaking better products, making them more efficiently, or moving in to more skilled activitieshas often been used in studies on petitiveness (Kaplinsky,2001; Porter, 1990), and is relevant here. Following this approach, upgrading is decisively related to innovation. Here we define upgrading as innovating to increase value added. 7 Enterprises achieve this in various ways, such as, for e*ample, by entering higher unit value market niches or new sectors, or by undertaking new productive (or service) functions. The concept of upgrading may be effectively described for enterprises working within a value chain, where four types of upgrading are singled out (Humphrey & Schmitz, 2000): Process upgrading is transforming inputs into outputs more efficiently by reorganizing the production system or introducing superior technology (e.g., footwear producers in the Sinos Valley; Schmitz, 1999b). Product upgrading is moving into more sophisticated product lines in terms of increased unit values (e.g., the apparel modity chain in Asia upgrading from discount chains to department stores; Gereffi,1999). Functional upgrading is acquiring new, superior functions in the chain, such as design or marketing or abandoning e*isting low-value added functions to focus on higher value added activities (e.g., Torreons blue jeans industry upgrading from maquila to full-package manufacturing; Bair&Gereffi, 2001). Inter sectoral upgrading is applying the petence acquired in a particular function to move into a new sector. For instance, in Taiwan, petence in producing TVs was used to make monitors and then to move into the puter sector (Guerrieri & Pietrobelli,2004; Humphrey & Schmitz,2002b). In sum, upgrading within a value 6 . z.-chain implies going up on the value ladder, moving away from activities in which petitionis of the low road type

    注意事项

    本文(经济金融企业管理外文翻译外文文献英文文献.doc)为本站会员(夺命阿水)主动上传,课桌文档仅提供信息存储空间,仅对用户上传内容的表现方式做保护处理,对上载内容本身不做任何修改或编辑。 若此文所含内容侵犯了您的版权或隐私,请立即通知课桌文档(点击联系客服),我们立即给予删除!

    温馨提示:如果因为网速或其他原因下载失败请重新下载,重复下载不扣分。




    备案号:宁ICP备20000045号-1

    经营许可证:宁B2-20210002

    宁公网安备 64010402000986号

    课桌文档
    收起
    展开